Instant Runoff Voting Explained

123
BAC
BAC
BAC
BCA
BCA
BD-
ABD
ABD
ABC
ADB
A--
DCB
DCA
D--
CAB
CDA
12
BA
BA
BA
BA
BA
BD
AB
AB
AB
AD
A-
DB
DA
D-
AB
DA
1
B
B
B
B
B
B
A
A
A
A
A
B
A
-
A
A

Instant Runoff Voting (IRV) is also known as the "Alternative Vote" and "Preferential Voting." Voters rank the candidates as first, second, third, etc. The tables to the left illustrate the IRV tallying procedure for an example with four candidates (A,B,C,D) and 16 voters. The leftmost table shows the original votes in sorted order (the last choice is not shown).

The first step is to count the first choices. Candidate B got 6 of the 16 first choices, while A got 5, D got 3, and C got 2. If one candidate had received a majority of first choices, that candidate would have won, but nobody did in this case. The counting procedure therefore goes to a second round.

The candidate with the fewest first choices, candidate C, is now eliminated. Each vote for C is transferred to the next candidate. Thus, all C entries are eliminated and the remaining choices are pushed left, if necessary, to fill in the empty cells. The middle table shows the result (the third column is no longer needed).

The top choices are now counted again. Candidate A gained one new top choice (the second from last vote) for a total of 6. Still no candidate has a majority, so the counting procedure goes to a third round. Candidate D now has the fewest top choices and is therefore eliminated. The rightmost table shows the result.

In the final round, the third from last vote has been exhausted, so only 15 active votes remain. Candidate A picked up two votes and now has 8 votes, which is a majority of the remaining votes, so candidate A wins. In this example, candidate A had fewer first choices than candidate B in the first round, but ultimately won the election.

The maximum number of rounds is always one less than the number of candidates. In the case of ties for the fewest top choices, the tied candidate with the fewest second choices is eliminated (if those are also tied, look at third choices, etc.). In the case of a tie in the final round, a coin toss can break the tie.

IRV has serious problems. It allows a sufficiently small minority of voters to safely register "protest" votes for minor-party candidates--but only as long as their candidate is sure to lose. As soon as their candidate threatens to actually win, they risk hurting their own cause by ranking their favorite first, just as they do under our current plurality system. IRV is therefore unlikely to be any more successful than plurality at solving the classic "lesser of two evils" problem.

A variation of IRV allows voters to rank groups of candidates equally. For example, a voter could rank candidates B and C equally for first choice, and D for second choice. For technical reasons that will not be discussed here, this equal-ranking option significantly mitigates the serious problems of IRV, but not enough to make it a good election method.

IRV does have one potential advantage over plurality. It requires the same voting equipment and the same voting mechanics (ranking candidates) as Condorcet voting. IRV could therefore possibly be transitional to Condorcet voting, a far superior alternative to IRV. However, IRV could also get entrenched and preclude Condorcet voting.

ElectionMethods.org