Voting Method Comparison Matrix Chart (version
10.3.16)
Created by Robin Quirke, Associate
Researcher, PolicyInteractive Research
Contact: info@policyinteractive.org
Additional matrices by Ka-Ping Yee here and by Warren D. Smith here
Voting System |
Ballot |
Winner |
Examples of Use |
Proposed Pros |
Proposed Cons |
Choose one
candidate |
Candidate with
most votes wins |
U.S.
presidential elections, most other U.S. state and local elections |
• Familiar • Simple • Maintains 2-party system • Does not require new ballots or voting
machinery |
• Minimally expressive of voter
preferences • Disadvantages third parties • Tends to squeeze out moderate candidates (see
computer simulation here) • Strategic voting (voting for less preferred
candidate to keep least preferred from winning) • Selecting more than one candidate
invalidates ballot (over-voting) • Maintains 2-party system • Winner may be disliked by a majority of
the population • Does not require absolute majority • Mathematical
model shows greatest mean
(average) of voter regret |
|
Choose
(approve of) as many candidates as you want |
Candidate with
most votes (most-approved candidate) wins |
U.N. secretary
general elections, American Statistical Association, American Mathematical
Association |
• More expressivity than plurality voting
(voters can say more about their candidate preferences) • Voters can safely vote honest favorite
(no need for strategic voting) • Does not require new ballots or voting
machinery/software • Proponents speculate it would increase
voter turnout |
• Unfamiliar • Not as expressive as range voting or
IRV • Does not require absolute majority • Lacks political momentum |
|
Score one or
more candidates on a scale (0-2, 1-5, 0-9, etc.) |
Candidate with
highest average score wins |
German Pirate
Party elections, Some Olympic
sports, Academic tests, Opinion
polling, Web based
product evaluations |
• Most expressivity of these four voting
systems (voters can say more about their candidate preferences) • Voters can safely vote honest favorite
(no need for strategic voting) • Proponents speculate it would increase
voter turnout • Proponents speculate it would reduce
the importance of money in politics • Proponents speculate it would gradually
reduce 2-party dominance • Mathematical
model suggests leads
to the least amount of voter regret |
• Unfamiliar • Information costs (rating more than one
candidate requires more voter knowledge) • Practically unused in political voting context • Lacks political momentum • May need new machines and/or software |
|
Voting System |
Ballot |
Winner |
Examples of Use |
Proposed Pros |
Proposed Cons |
Rank each
candidate in order of preference (1st, 2nd, etc.) Most
jurisdictions limit choice to ranking three places for simplicity even if
there are more candidates running, while other jurisdictions allow all
candidates to be ranked. |
Candidate with a majority of first place votes wins. If
no candidate acquires an initial absolute majority (more than half the votes)
counting moves to another round (runoff) where the candidate with the fewest
number of first-preference rankings is eliminated and these prior round votes
redistributed, the process being repeated until a candidate that achieves the
required majority
within any specific round of counting, wins. Caveat:
reaching an "absolute voter majority" is a theoretical requirement, but not
always a reality in U.S. IRV elections. |
Local
elections in several U.S. cities (e.g., San Francisco, Minneapolis), Oscar
Best Picture, Australian Parliament elections, City of London, |
• More expressivity than plurality voting
(voters can say more about their candidate preferences) • Voters can vote honest favorite • Lowers some costs associated with
two-round system elections (e.g., common in California elections, see California Proposition 14) • Proponents claim it reduces negative
campaigning • Proponents claim it increases voter
turnout • Strongest political momentum of the voting
alternatives |
• Unfamiliar to many • Complex calculation process • Confusion has led to over-voting and
under-voting (more eliminated ballots) • Information costs (ranking more than
one candidate requires more voter knowledge) • Voter fatigue in the ranking process • Critics claim decreases voter turnout • Critics worry combining two elections
(e.g., two-round system in California) into one reduces public exposure to
candidate positions on issues • Less sophisticated voters tend to be
marginalized (e.g., choose not to vote at all, ballots disqualified because
of over or under-voting) • Constitutional challenges • Can be expensive to implement • Creates a false majority (e.g., 3rd
ranked choices can get redistributed as a 1st ranked choices; many
ballots are disqualified) • Practicing jurisdictions experience
time delays if runoff is necessary (not ÒinstantÓ; have to wait for ballots
from least popular candidates to be redistributed) • Potential security problems if using
computerized voting system (hacking) • Manual recount and verification
difficult • Tends to squeeze out moderate candidates (see
software engineerÕs computer simulation with explanation here) • Has not reduced 2-party dominance in Australia • Winner-turns-loser paradox (because of
redistribution of ballots, increases in popularity can cause a winner to
lose, and decreases can cause a loser to win; see example here, page 11) |
Resources:
Brams, S. J., & Fishburn, P. C.
(2005). Going from theory to practice: the mixed success of approval voting. Social Choice and Welfare, 25, 457-474.
Burnett, C. M., & Kogan, V.
(2015). Ballot (and voter) "exhaustion" under Instant
Runoff Voting: An examination of four ranked-choice elections. Electoral Studies, 37, 41-49.
Endersby, J. W., & Towle, M. J. (2014). Making wasted votes count: Turnout,
transfers, and preferential voting in practice. Electoral Studies, 33,
144-152.
Langan, J. P. (2004).
Instant runoff voting: a cure that is
likely worse than the disease. Wm. &
Mary Law Rev., 46, 1569.
McDaniel, J. A. (2015).
Writing the Rules to Rank the Candidates: Examining the Impact of
Instant-Runoff Voting on Racial Group Turnout in San Francisco Mayoral Elections.
Journal of Urban Affairs 38,3 p.387-408.
Marron, B. P. (2003).
One
person, one vote, several elections: Instant runoff voting and the
constitution. Vermont Law Rev., 28, 343.
Neely, F., & Cook, C. (2008).
Whose votes count? Undervotes, overvotes, and
ranking in San Francisco's instant-runoff elections. American Politics Research, 36,4, 530-554.
Ornstein, J. T., & Norman, R. Z. (2014).
Frequency of
monotonicity failure under Instant Runoff Voting: estimates based on a spatial
model of elections. Public Choice, 161, 1-9.
http://www.fairvote.org (proponents of IRV)
https://electology.org (proponents of approval and range/score voting)
(proponents of approval and range/score voting)
Exit polls: http://archive.fairvote.org/?page=2170
Online news articles:
http://californiawatch.org/dailyreport/ranked-choice-voting-complaints-mount-6839
https://psmag.com/the-curious-and-complexifying-ranked-choice-voting-system-4fc332a85ef1#.2etoglmq0
http://www.wral.com/instant-runoff-results-not-so-instant/8563987/
http://abc7news.com/politics/ranked-choice-voting-could-delay-oakland-mayoral-race-outcome-/380826/