Is Condorcet Voting Too Complicated?
By far the most common initial reaction to the Condorcet voting concept is that it is "too
complicated" to be approved for public elections. Is it? Well, yes and
no. Yes, it is too complicated for a public that is almost
completely ignorant of alternative election methods. But for a public
that is educated on the major democratic advantages of Condorcet voting,
it is exactly as complicated as it needs to be. The purpose of this
website is to provide that education.
Yes, Condorcet voting seems complicated at first. But so did many
other mathematical concepts we take for granted. If written out in
detail, for example, the instructions for multiplying and dividing
decimal numbers by hand would certainly seem complicated -- particularly
for those with no previous exposure to it. Yet anyone who complained
that division is "too complicated" to be trusted for critical
applications would be dismissed as an idiot. The Condorcet election
rules are arguably less complicated than multiplication and
division.
More importantly, voters need not remember or even understand the
rules of Condorcet voting any more than they need to remember the rules
of long division to divide numbers with a calculator. All they really
need to understand is that, unlike any other election method, Condorcet
allows them to vote sincerely without the risk of hurting their own
cause. But good citizens should understand their voting system,
of course, just as educated people should understand how to
multiply and divide numbers by hand.
The complexity of Condorcet voting comes in two parts. The first part
is in interpreting the rankings on each ballot as an equivalent pairwise
matrix; the second is in resolving cyclical ambiguities when necessary.
The determination of pairwise matrices is very basic and should be
understandable with moderate effort by eighth-graders. The resolution of
cyclical ambiguities is slightly more complicated, but it should be
understandable with very moderate effort by average high school juniors.
If that level of intellectual effort is now too much to ask for
something as fundamental as a superior election method, democracy is in
trouble.
The real problem with Condorcet voting is not so much that it is too
complicated, but rather that it is perceived as such, usually
by those who have little difficulty understanding it themselves, but who
assume it is too complicated for the masses. Because it takes a few
minutes to explain, they assume that the masses will not pay attention
long enough to comprehend it. But the masses will be much more
interested in Condorcet voting when they become aware of its fundamental
importance to the advancement of democracy. Until that time, they are
likely to regard it as some arbitrary crackpot scheme, and they will
have little incentive to pay attention.
The implementation strategy, therefore, requires at least two major
steps. First, a consensus must be developed, among those interested in
election methods, that Condorcet voting is indeed a superior method in
principle, regardless of how difficult it will be to sell to the
general public. After that consensus is reached, the job of selling
it to the general public can be effective. Private polling organizations
can then begin experimenting with it to determine which candidates the
public really prefers. When the general public finally wakes up
and realizes that Condorcet voting can finally give them the kind of
leaders they really want, they will pressure politicians to take
action.
ElectionMethods.org |